Volume 40, Number 3, April 2008

Ana Maria Evans, "Preemptive Modernization and the Politics of Sectoral Defense: Adjustment to Globalization in the Portuguese Pharmacy Sector"

Small firms in the Portuguese pharmacy sector have adjusted remarkably well to regional economic integration, in contrast to the response of other small retailers to the challenges of political and economic liberalization. It is possible for old sectors of small firms to adjust to globalization and preserve individual ownership through an extended politics of sectoral defense. Key strategic elements and institutional preconditions make this politics possible. The article draws on field research on the pharmacy and food retail sectors in Portugal and theoretical analyses on neocorporatism, the third Italy, and varieties of capitalism.

Robert G. Moser, "Electoral Systems and the Representation of Ethnic Minorities: Evidence from Russia"

Does proportional representation produce greater minority representation than single member districts? This question can be studied through the ethnic background of legislators elected in the two tiers of the mixed electoral system in Russia. In general, there is no significant difference in the level of minority representation in proportional representation and single member district contests. However, electoral systems have different effects for different ethnic groups. Proportional representation does not provide increased minority representation in party systems devoid of ethnic parties. Moreover, the relationship between minority representation and electoral system is conditioned by the minorities’ demographic and cultural characteristics.

Henry E. Hale, "The Double-Edged Sword of Ethnofederalism: Ukraine and the USSR in Comparative Perspective"

Ethnofederalism has been blamed for secessionism in the USSR, Yugoslavia, and Czechoslovakia, yet it is also touted as an important way of preventing ethnic conflict. Indeed, ethnofederalism is a double-edged sword, potentially generating both centrifugal and centripetal dynamics. Which way it ultimately cuts depends not only on context and institutions, but also on the undertheorized factor of leadership strategy. A focused process-tracing comparison of four time periods in the most challenging case of Ukraine, each corresponding to a different Soviet leadership strategy, confirms the theory and challenges the common wisdom that secessionism was inexorably rising in the USSR during the year of its disintegration.

Zeynep Somer-Topcu and Laron K. Williams, "Survival of the Fittest? Cabinet Duration in Postcommunist Europe"

Governments in postcommunist Europe are not slaves to their institutions, unable to extend their time in office beyond the constraints imposed by their institutional arrangement. Cabinet duration is tied to performance in office, characterized by economic success. Duration models show that governments in postcommunist Europe are similar to those in western Europe, even though some states lack party institutionalization and strong partisan attachments. Institutional arrangements, including the effective number of parties in government and the type of government, combine with economic performance to affect the survival rates of postcommunist governments.

Amos Zehavi, "The Faith-Based Initiative in Comparative Perspective: Making Use of Religious Providers in Britain and the United States"

Historically, faith-based organizations made important contributions in the field of social provision, but with the advent of the modern welfare state their role diminished dramatically. Why has there been renewed interest in the United States and Britain in publicly funded faith-based social provision. Despite significant differences between the two countries, their governments have endorsed strikingly similar faith-based initiatives that have institutionalized the relationship between the state and faith-based organizations. The emergence of faith-based initiatives is one component of welfare state restructuring, more specifically, a response to the growing problem of minority social exclusion in urban areas.

Review Article: Teresa Wright, "State-Society Relations in Reform-Era China: A Unique Case of Postsocialist State-Led Development?"

Contrary to many expectations, both capital and labor in China seem to have come to accept–and even support–Chinese Communist rule. Recent works by Bruce Dickson, Mary Gallagher, and Yongshun Cai help to explain why. Simultaneously, the findings of scholars outside of China suggest that the larger answer lies in China’s combination of state-led late development and socialist past. Unlike in earlier developers, the emergence of capitalism in China has brought both greater economic inequality and new forms of dependence on the state. Further, as in postsocialist Russia and East and Central Europe, Chinese citizens show a preference for socialist economic values. Consequently, for both rising and declining sectors, China’s economic reform has created disincentives to oppose the authoritarian political status quo.
Volume 40, Number 3, April 20082018-07-04T20:43:38+00:00

Volume 40, Number 2, January 2008

John Sidel, "Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy Revisited: Colonial State and Chinese Immigrant in the Making of Modern Southeast Asia"

Barrington Moore, Jr., argued that a vigorous and independent bourgeoisie is a necessary, if insufficient, condition for democracy. This article addresses this thesis through a comparative analysis of class formation in Southeast Asia. Colonial era state policies towards immigrant Chinese merchant minorities shaped the diverging capacities and inclinations of capitalist classes in the region to assert themselves in political life and to assume control over state power. The variegated identities and strengths of the capitalist classes of Southeast Asia have prefigured enduring authoritarian rule in most countries in the region over the past several decades, while enabling democratic rule in the Philippines, Thailand, and, in recent years, Indonesia.

Frances Hagopian, "Latin American Catholicism in an Age of Religious and Political Pluralism: A Framework for Analysis"

This article identifies and proposes a framework to explain the responses of Latin America’s Roman Catholic churches to a new strategic dilemma posed by religious and political pluralism. Because the church’s goals of defending institutional interests, evangelizing, promoting public morality, and grounding public policy in Catholic social teaching cut across existing political cleavages, church leaders must make strategic choices about which to emphasize in their messages to the faithful, investment of pastoral resources, and alliances. The article presents a typology of episcopal responses based on Argentina, Chile, Brazil, and Mexico and explains strategic choices by the church’s capacity to mobilize civil society, its degree of religious hegemony, and the ideological orientations of Catholics.

Gary L Goodman and Jonathan T. Hiskey, "Exit without Leaving: Political Disengagement in High Migration Municipalities in Mexico"

As Mexico continues to democratize amid an unprecedented wave of migration, the increasing levels of migration have affected the political attitudes and behaviors of those left behind. Municipal and individual level data strongly attest to the process of disengagement among citizens in high migration municipalities from the national political system as a transnational community comes to the fore. High migration municipalities exhibit lower voter turnout rates, and individuals in high migration areas report lower levels of political efficacy, participate less in politics, and rely more on participation in local community groups than their counterparts in less migratory towns.

Ozge Kemahlioglu, "Particularistic Distribution of Investment Subsidies under coalition Governments: The Case of Turkey"

Governments can provide investment subsidies to private business to stimulate growth and production. Rent seeking by politicians has threatened the success of this strategy especially in developing countries like Turkey. Particularistic allocation of these subsidies by politicians has been a concern, but the influence of electoral incentives on these particularistic exchanges has not been systematically analyzed. Responsibility sharing and credit claiming mechanisms under coalition governments are expected to give different electoral incentives to politicians. Investment subsidies in Turkey between 1992 and 1997 reveal that districts where the coalition partner that is not in control of distributing subsidies is strong have received a relatively smaller number of subsidies.

Lianjiang Li, "Political Trust and Petitioning in the Chinese Countryside"

What is the significance of distinguishing trust in government’s commitment from trust in its competence in understanding the relationship between political trust and political participation? Chinese farmers have more trust in the central government’s commitment to protect their rights and interests than in its capacity to do so. Trust in the center’s competence carries more weight than trust in its commitment in accounting for the propensity to petition. Petitioning tends to weaken trust in the center’s capacity as well as trust in its commitment. Distrust in the center’s commitment enhances the propensity to engage in more assertive forms of political participation.

Review Article: Lisa Hilbink, "Assessing the New Constitutionalism"

Initial scholarly exuberance over the global spread of bills of rights and judicial review has given way to a spate of studies that bemoan the trend as fundamentally antidemocratic. This review offers an empirically informed critique of these new, more skeptical studies. It highlights ways in which selection and tenure rules for high court judges vary across cases, describes a number of institutional mechanisms designed to mitigate judicial supremacy in different countries, and offers examples of the ways that some new constitutionalist countries have sought to facilitate popular access to courts and to charge courts with protecting popular interests. More comparative work on the effects of this variation on political practice and policy outcomes would be welcome.
Volume 40, Number 2, January 20082018-07-04T20:43:39+00:00

Volume 40, Number 1, October 2007

J. Samuel Valenzuela, Timothy R. Scully, and Nicolás Somma, "The Enduring Presence of Religion in Chilean Ideological Positionings and Voter Options"

Pinochet’s dictatorship is widely believed to have changed Chilean politics by creating a new authoritarian/democratic political cleavage that reorganized the party system and voter alignments. However, religious and class differences have not lost their salience in determining political attitudes in Chile. An original survey focusing primarily on religion shows that religion continues to mold political views along three polarities: irreligion versus religiosity, Catholicism versus Protestantism, and progressive versus traditional forms of religiosity. The irreligious, Protestants, and religiously progressive Catholics place themselves more to the left and are more supportive of the Concertation coalition. Class differences also remain important.

Christina Davis and Jennifer Oh, "Repeal of the Rice Laws in Japan: The Role of International Pressure to Overcome Vested Interests"

Agriculture has long been one of the most protected sectors in advanced industrial democracies. The rural biases of electoral systems, high organization by farmer interest groups, and an autonomous policy community have allowed agriculture to resist reform. However, market principles and partial liberalization have begun to be introduced. Japan has one of the highest levels of agricultural protection. Political changes, budget constraints, consumer demands, and international pressure all pushed for a major overhaul of Japanese agricultural policies, but international pressure was necessary to produce substantive reforms. International agreements, in particular, play a major role in bringing about domestic reforms in policy areas with strong vested interests.

Linda J. Cook, "Negotiating Welfare in Postcommunist States"

During the postcommunist transition, inherited welfare states came under intense pressures to retrench and restructure. Most governments initiated reform projects based on a liberal paradigm of reduced entitlements and social sector privatization, moving welfare away from the state toward the market. Yet the patterns of reform diverged in puzzling ways, producing distinct trajectories of change and outcomes. Case studies of three postcommunist states show that the political influence of societal and state-based welfare stakeholders was a key factor in welfare state change. Where political institutions gave stakeholders access, they moderated reforms during recession and sustained a predominant state role in welfare after economic recovery. Where stakeholders were weak, reformist executives retrenched and restructured with little constraint.

Wim van Oorschot and Wilfred Uunk, "Welfare Spending and the Public's Concern for Immigrants: Multilevel Evidence for Eighteen European Countries"

How does a nation’s welfare spending affect people’s concern for immigrants in comparison with other needy groups? Economic self-interest and cultural ideology theory and knowledge about immigration rates in welfare states suggest several hypotheses. Multilevel regression analyses of data for eighteen countries from the European Values Survey 1999/2000 demonstrate that a nation’s welfare spending positively affects people’s relative concern for immigrants. However, it is not the level of welfare spending itself but rather the level of immigration that makes people relatively more concerned. These findings suggest that fears of tensions about welfare redistribution toward immigrants is not justified in European countries.

Christian Albrekt Larsen, "How Welfare Regimes Generate and Erode Social Capital: The Impact of Underclass Phenomena"

Comparative studies of social capital, operationalized as social trust between citizens, have revealed two major puzzles. First, why has social capital eroded in the U.S. and other liberal welfare regimes, while it is stable in social democratic and conservative welfare regimes? Second, why does the group of social democratic regimes have extremely high levels of social trust? The answer to both puzzles lies in the presence or absence of a poor and culturally distinct underclass. The social democratic welfare regimes hinder, while the liberal welfare regimes generate, such underclass phenomena.

Review Article: Veljko Vujačić, "Elites, Narratives, and Nationalist Mobilization in the Former Yugoslavia"

This article reviews four recent books on nationalist mobilization and ethnic violence in the former Yugoslavia. The focus on political elites as instigators of ethnic conflict is too narrow. A fully adequate causal explanation of ethnic violence requires closer attention to contextual factors, especially competing nationalist narratives as elaborated by religious and secular intellectual elites. Because nationalist myths, symbols, and narratives play a greater role in nationalist mobilization than in class or issue-specific politics, causal explanations of nationalist mobilization must satisfy Weber’s requirement of  adequacy on the level of meaning. Theoretically driven generalizations have a limited explanatory potential in explaining specific instances of nationalist mobilization.
Volume 40, Number 1, October 20072018-07-04T20:43:39+00:00

Volume 39, Number 4, July 2007

Niall Ó Murchú, "Split Labor Markets and Ethnic Violence after World War I: A Comparison of Belfast, Chicago, and Johannesburg"

This article compares ethnic competition in the labor market and ethnic violence in Belfast, Chicago, and Johannesburg after World War I using Bonacich’s split labor market theory of ethnic antagonism. Augmented by an analysis of the dominant groups’ power in the workplace and the state, the theory proves quite robust in explaining postwar labor market outcomes in shipbuilding (exclusion), meatpacking (displacement), and gold mining (caste building). However, it remains inadequate in explaining interethnic violence, such as the Belfast workplace expulsions (1920), the Chicago race riot (1919), and the Rand Revolt (1922), which exceeded the bounds of the labor market. The split labor market approach is valuable in explaining segmentation but not as a general theory of ethnic antagonism.

Martin Höpner, "Corporate Governance Reform and the German Party Paradox"

Why do German Social Democrats opt for more corporate governance liberalization than the Christian Democrats, although in terms of the distributional outcomes of such reforms the situation should be reversed? This empirical puzzle seems to contradict insights from comparative political economy and the varieties of capitalism approach, in particular. Social Democrats and trade unions adopted their liberal attitude to company regulation after World War II. In the 1970s competition policy was introduced to make Keynesian macroeconomic policy work. Since the 1990s labor favored shareholder-oriented reforms because they helped employee representatives in conflicts over managerial control. The analysis has implications for partisan theory, institutional complementarity, and conflict models in comparative political economy.

Brian D. Taylor, "Force and Federalism: Controlling Coercion in Federal Hybrid Regimes"

Studies of federalism ascribe a central role to coercion in the birth and death of federations. In contrast, the role of force almost completely disappears when the focus shifts to the management of federations. However, in conditions faced by many federal hybrid regimes, the institutions said to manage federal relations’ political parties, constitutions, and judiciaries’ often are too weak to fulfill this role successfully. Thus, control coercion may play an important role in resolving center-subunit disputes. Securing control over coercive power has been a prominent feature of federal relations in post-Soviet Russia. Despite the weakness of coercion as a mechanism of regulating the federal bargain, certain modes of organizing force may assist federal stabilization, at least until parties and courts develop a stronger capacity to play this role.

Dinissa Duvanova, "Bureaucratic Corruption and Collective Action: Business Associations in the Postcommunist Transition"

Corruption is a notorious companion of the postcommunist economic transition, and it has had an adverse effect on business. Does corruption also inhibit collective action among postcommunist firms? Based on an analysis of survey data on membership in business associations in twenty-five postcommunist countries, and controlling for other factors affecting group membership, firms’ perception of bureaucratic corruption is positively associated with membership. This finding is quite surprising, given the conventional understanding of business-state relations. Causal mechanisms linking bureaucratic corruption to association formation can be traced through the development of two business associations. Business associations attract their members by providing effective mechanisms to confront bureaucratic corruption.

Sandra F. Joireman, "Enforcing New Property Rights in Sub-Saharan Africa: The Ugandan Constitution and the 1998 Land Act"

Many sub-Saharan African countries are embarking on major changes in their property rights law with the goal of achieving more vigorous economic growth and alleviating poverty. Uganda has been at the forefront of these changes with constitutional change and a new land law. The Ugandan land law encapsulates recent efforts to formalize existing informal property rights. Implementation and enforcement of the 1998 Land Act are examined through paired case studies. There have been three major impediments to implementation: lack of capacity, corruption, and customary law. While the new land law has been necessary to change property rights, it has faced obstacles in its implementation that undermine secure property rights to land.

Review Article: Sabine Saurugger, "Collective Action in the European Union: From Interest Group Influence to Participation in Democracy"

Review of three recent books on collective action and interest group activity in the European Union offers an opportunity to analyze the development of interest group studies in relation to European integration. A feasible research agenda can build on the works under review. Scholars can incorporate a sensitivity to the impact of collective action on democracy, particularly on citizens’ participation in their national and supranational polities. In this respect, EU interest group studies can be linked more clearly to questions developed by comparative political approaches elsewhere and thus become a mainstream aspect of EU research.
Volume 39, Number 4, July 20072018-07-04T20:43:40+00:00

Volume 39, Number 3, April 2007

Eduardo Alemán and Sebastián Saiegh, "Legislative Preferences, Political Parties, and Coalition Unity in Chile"

Competition between two stable multiparty coalitions has dominated electoral and legislative politics in post-Pinochet Chile. However, several scholars dispute the argument that a fundamental change has realigned the party system. The point of contention is whether a bipolar pattern has replaced the traditional three-way split (tres tercios) in political competition. These alternative hypotheses about the cohesion of parties and coalitions in the legislative arena can be tested through an analysis of the voting records of Chilean deputies. Coalition membership rather than partisan positions dictate legislative behavior. Therefore, the Chilean electoral coalitions are not merely electoral pacts. Rather, they constitute two distinct policy-based coalitions.

Christoffer Green-Pedersen, "The Conflict of Conflicts in Comparative Perspective: Euthanasia as a Political Issue in Denmark, Belgium, and the Netherlands"

Political science has never paid much comparative attention to what Schattschneider called the “conflict of conflicts.” However, this question is becoming increasingly important as the conflict structure in many western countries is breaking up. Is the ability to link an issue to an already existing conflict in the party system crucial for it to become a political issue? This question is addressed through a study of the issue of euthanasia in Denmark, Belgium, and the Netherlands. Euthanasia became a political issue in the Netherlands and Belgium because it was linked to the religious/secular conflict in the party system. As a consequence of the politicization, the Netherlands and Belgium have legalized euthanasia.

Anthony Mughan, "Economic Insecurity and Welfare Preferences: A Micro-Level Analysis"

Economic insecurity is commonly held to be the key psychological mechanism underpinning the relationship between rapid economic change and the size of welfare states. Transformations like deindustrialization and globalization are held to create winners and losers, and the latter demand greater governmental protection against the forces undermining their economic insecurity. This individual-level relationship has been assumed rather than specified and tested. Economic insecurity can take more than one form. Moreover, its different forms vary not only in their socioeconomic roots, but also in their relationship to support for enhanced social protection. A comparison of the United States and Australia highlights the variability of economic insecurity’s impact of welfare preferences and the need to unpack the complexity of their relationship.

Lucy Mansergh and Robert Thomson, "Election Pledges, Party Competition, and Policymaking"

Election pledges are made on important issues and on the policy themes parties emphasize most. Pledges made by parties that enter the government after elections are more likely to be enacted than those made by parties that do not. Substantial differences in rates of pledge enactment can be found among majoritarian, coalition, and bicameral systems. New evidence on elections in Ireland, where coalition governments are common, is compared with the Netherlands, the U.K., the U.S., Canada, and Greece. Ireland and the Netherlands are crucial cases for theories of cabinet governance that feature the coalition agreement and the allocation of ministerial portfolios.

Devashree Gupta, "Selective Engagement and Its Consequences for Social Movement Organizations: Lessons from British Policy in Northern Ireland"

How do governments respond to the demands of different social movement organizations? They respond selectively, embracing some movement groups as acceptable bargaining partners, while sidelining or repressing others. Thus, they create uneven political opportunity structures that prompt organizations to pursue divergent protest strategies. Selective engagement is a double-edged sword. Groups that forge a closer relationship with state actors can benefit from increased access, but they also face shorter time horizons to deliver change and risk alienating their members. Over time, these side effects can minimize the worth of “desirable” groups to governments, while making it possible for organizations previously left out of the process to increase their clout and demand entry.

Review Article: Antonis A. Ellinas, "Phased Out: Far Right Parties in Western Europe"

Much like earlier studies of the far right, recent scholarship asks why far right parties advanced in some West European democracies but not in others, but its answers differ. Socioeconomic explanations, which dominated earlier studies, are now only the starting point to explain the electoral trajectories of the far right. Recent scholarship lays more emphasis on the domestic political setting, examining the effects of party competition, organization, and appeals. Moreover, it attempts to correct the earlier neglect of electoral institutions. Its findings do not yield firm conclusions about the drivers of far right performance, but the theoretical implications are too important to miss. Future scholarship must pay closer attention to temporal variation in far right performance.
Volume 39, Number 3, April 20072018-07-04T20:43:40+00:00
Go to Top